How would you account for the difference in perspective between firms who often complain of government over-interference in business matters and ministers who
How would you account for the difference in perspective between firms who often complain of government over-interference in business matters and ministers who
IIBMS ANSWER SHEETS
IIBMS MBA CASE STUDY ANSWER SHEETS,
IIBMS MBA CASE STUDY SOLUTIONS,
IIBMS EMBA CASE STUDY ANSWER SHEETS,
IIBMS EMBA CASE STUDY SOLUTIONS,
IIBMS DMS CASE STUDY ANSWER SHEETS,
IIBMS DMS CASE STUDY SOLUTIONS,
IIBMS MMS CASE STUDY ANSWER SHEETS,
IIBMS MIB CASE STUDY SOLUTIONS,
MBA IIBMS ANSWER SHEETS,
EMBA IIBMS CASE STUDY SOLUTIONS.
www.answersheets.in
info.answersheets@gmail.com
info@answersheets.in
+91 95030-94040
Business Environment
Attempt Any Four
Case Study
Case Study 1 : Structuring global companies
As the chapter
illustrates, to carry out their activities in pursuit of their objectives, virtually all
organisations adopt some form of organisational structure. One traditional method of
organisation is to group individuals by function or purpose, using a departmental structure
to allocate individuals to their specialist areas (e.g. Marketing, HRM and so on
). Another is to group activities by product or service, with each product group
normally responsible for providing its own functional requirements. A third is
to combine the two in the form of a matrix structure with its vertical and
horizontal flows of responsibility and authority, a method of organisation much
favoured in university Business Schools.
What of companies with a
global reach: how do they usually organise them- selves?
Writing in the Financial
Times in November 2000 Julian Birkinshaw, Associate Professor of Strategic and
International Management at London Business School, identifies four basic
models of global company structure:
● The International
Division - an arrangement in which the company establishes a separate division
to deal with business outside
its own country.
The International
Division would typically be concerned with tariff and trade issues, foreign agents/partners
and other aspects involved in selling overseas. Normally the division does not make
anything itself, it is simply responsible for interna-tional sales. This
arrangement tends to be found in medium-sized companies with limited international
sales. The Global Product
Division - a product-based structure with managers responsible for their product line
globally. The company is split into a number of global busi-nesses arranged by product
(or service) and usually overseen by their own president. It has been a favoured structure among large
global companies such as BP, Siemens and 3M. ● The Area Division - a geographically based structure in which the major
line of
authority lies with the country (e.g. Germany) or regional (e.g. Europe) manager who is responsible for the different product offerings within her/his geographical area.
authority lies with the country (e.g. Germany) or regional (e.g. Europe) manager who is responsible for the different product offerings within her/his geographical area.
● The Global Matrix - as
the name suggests a hybrid of the two previous structural types. In the global matrix each business manager reports to two bosses,
one responsible for the global
product and one for the country/region. As we indi-cated in the previous
edition of this book, this type of structure tends to come into and go out of
fashion. Ford, for example, adopted a matrix structure in the later 1990s, while a
number of other global companies were either streamlining or dismantling theirs
(e.g. Shell, BP, IBM). As Professor Birkinshaw indicates, ultimately there is no perfect
structure and organisations tend
to change their approach over time according to changing circumstances, fads,
the perceived needs
of the senior
executives or the predispositions of powerful individuals. This observation is no less true
of universities than it is of traditional businesses.
Case study questions
1.
Professor Birkinshaw’s article identifies the advantages
and disadvantages of being a
global business. What are his major arguments?
2.
In your opinion what are likely to be the key factors
determining how a global company will organise itself?
Case 2 : Resource prices
As we saw in Chapter 1,
resources such as labour, technology and raw materials constitute inputs into
the production process that are utilised by organisations to produce outputs. Apart
from concerns over the quality, quantity and availability of the different factors of
production, businesses are also interested in the issue of input prices since these
represent costs to the organisation which ultimately have to be met from
revenues if the business is to survive. As in any other market, the prices of economic
resources can change over time for a variety of reasons, most, if not all, of which are
outside the direct control of business organisations. Such fluc-tuations in
input prices can be illustrated by the following examples:
● Rising labour costs -
e.g. rises in wages or salaries and other labour-related costs (such as pension
contributions or healthcare schemes) that are not offset by increases in productivity
or changes in working practices. Labour costs could rise for a variety of reasons
including skills shortages, demographic pressures, the introduction of a national
minimum wage or workers seeking to maintain their living standards in an
inflationary period.
● Rising raw material costs
- e.g. caused by increases in the demand for certain raw materials and/or shortages
(or bottlenecks) in supply. It can also be the result of the need to switch to
more expensive raw material sources because of customer pressure, environmental
considerations or lack of availability.
● Rising energy costs -
e.g. caused by demand and/or supply problems as in the oil market in recent years,
with growth in India and China helping to push up demand and coinciding with
supply difficulties linked to events such as the war in Iraq, hurricanes in the Gulf of Mexico or decisions by
OPEC.
● Increases in the cost of purchasing new technology/capital equipment - e.g. caused by the need to compete with rivals or to meet more stringent government gulations in areas such as health and safety or the environment.
As the above examples
illustrate, rising input prices can be the result of factors operating at both the micro
and macro level and these can range from events which are linked to natural causes to developments of a
political, social and/or economic kind. While many of these influences in the business environment
are uncontrollable, there are
steps business organisations can (and do) often take to address the issue of
rising input prices that may threaten their competitiveness. Examples include the
following:
● Seeking cheaper sources
of labour (e.g. Dyson moved its production of vacuum cleaners to the Far East).
● Abandoning salary-linked
pension schemes or other fringe benefits (e.g. com-pany cars, healthcare
provisions, paid holidays).
● Outsourcing certain
activities (e.g. using call centres to handle customer com- plaints, or outsourcing services such as security, catering, cleaning,
payroll, etc.).
● Switching raw materials
or energy suppliers (e.g. to take advantage of discounts by entering into longer
agreements to purchase).
● Energy-saving measures
(e.g. through better insulation, more regular servicing of equipment, product
and/or process redesign).
● Productivity gains (e.g.
introducing incentive schemes).
In addition to measures
such as these, some organisations seek cost savings through divestment of parts of the
business or alternatively through merger or takeover activity. In the former
case the aim tends to be to focus on the organisation’s core products/services and to
shed unprofitable and/or costly activities; in the latter the objective is usually to
take advantage of economies of scale, particularly those asso-ciated with
purchasing, marketing, administration and financing the business.
Case study questions
1.
If a company is
considering switching production to a country where wage costs are lower, what other factors will it need
to take into account before doing so?
2.
Will increased environmental standards imposed by government on
businesses inevitably result in
higher business costs?
Case 3 :
Government and business - friend or foe?
As we have seen,
governments intervene in the day-to-day working of the economy in a variety of ways in
the hope of improving the environment in which industrial and commercial activity
takes place. How far they are successful in achieving this goal is open to question.
Businesses, for example, frequently complain of over-interference by
governments and of the burdens
imposed upon them
by government legislation
and regulation. Ministers, in contrast, tend to stress how they have helped to
create an environment conducive to entrepreneurial activity through the different policy initiatives and through a supportive legal and
fiscal regime. Who is right? While there is no simple answer to this question, it is instructive to
examine the different surveys
which are regularly undertaken of business attitudes and condi-tions in different
countries. One such survey by the European Commission - and reported by Andrew Osborn
in the Guardian on 20 November 2001 - claimed that whereas countries such as
Finland, Luxembourg, Portugal and the Netherlands tended to be regarded as
business-friendly, the United Kingdom was perceived as the most difficult and
complicated country to do business with in the whole of Europe. Foreign firms
evidently claimed that the UK was harder to trade with than other countries owing to
its bureaucratic procedures and its tendency to rigidly enforce business
regulations. EU officials singled out Britain’s complex tax formali-ties, employment
regulations and product conformity rules as particular problems for foreign companies -
criticisms which echo those of the CBI and other represen-tative bodies who have
been complaining of the cost of over-regulation to UK firms over a considerable
number of years. The news, however, is not all bad. The Competitive Alternatives study
(2002) by KPMG of costs in various
cities in the G7 countries, Austria and the Netherlands indicated that Britain is
the second cheapest place in which to do business in the nine industrial countries
(see www.competitivealternatives.com). The survey, which looked at a range of
business costs - especially labour costs and taxation -, placed the UK second behind
Canada world-wide and in first place within Europe. The country’s strong showing
largely reflected its competitive labour costs, with manu-facturing costs estimated
to be 12.5 per cent lower than in Germany and 20 per cent lower than many other
countries in continental Europe. Since firms frequently use this survey to
identify the best places to locate their business, the data on rela-tive costs are likely to
provide the UK with a competitive advantage in the battle for foreign inward
investment (see Mini case, above).
Case study questions
1.
How would you account for the
difference in perspective between firms who often complain of government
over-interference in business matters and ministers who claim that they have the
interests of business at heart when taking decisions?
2.
To what extent do you think that relative costs are the critical factor
in determining inward investment
decisions?
Case 4 : The end of the block exemption
As we have seen in the
chapter, governments frequently use laws and regulations to promote competition within
the marketplace in the belief that this has significant benefits for the consumer
and for the economy generally. Such interventions occur not only at national
level, but also in situations where governments work together to provide mutual
benefits, as in the European Union’s attempts to set up a ‘Single Market’
across the member states of the EU. While few would deny that
competitive markets have many benefits, the search for increased competition
at national level and beyond can sometimes be restrained by the political realities of the situation, a
point underlined by a previous decision of the EU authorities to allow a block
exemption from the normal rules of competition in the EU car market. Under this
system, motor manufacturers operat-
ing within the EU were permitted to create networks of selective and exclusive dealerships and to engage in certain other activities normally outlawed under the competition provisions of the single market. It was argued that the system of selective and exclusive distribution (SED) benefited consumers by providing them with a cradle-to-grave service, alongside what was said to be a highly competitive supply situation within the heavily branded global car market.
ing within the EU were permitted to create networks of selective and exclusive dealerships and to engage in certain other activities normally outlawed under the competition provisions of the single market. It was argued that the system of selective and exclusive distribution (SED) benefited consumers by providing them with a cradle-to-grave service, alongside what was said to be a highly competitive supply situation within the heavily branded global car market.
Introduced in 1995, and
extended until the end of September 2002, the block exemption was highly
criticised for its impact on the operation of the car market in Europe. Following a
critical report by the UK competition authorities in April 2000, the EU published a review
(in November 2000) of the workings of the existing arrangement for distributing
and servicing cars, highlighting its adverse conse-quences for both consumers
and retailers and signalling the need for change.
Despite intensive lobbying by the
major car manufacturers, and by some national govern-ments, to maintain the
current rules largely intact, the European Commission announced its intention of
replacing the block exemption regulation when it expired in September, subject
of course to consultation with interested parties. In essence the
Commission’s proposals aimed to give dealers far more independ- ence from suppliers by
allowing them to solicit for business anywhere in the EU and to open showrooms
wherever they want; they would also be able to sell cars supplied by different
manufacturers under the same roof. The plan also sought to open up the aftersales
market by breaking the tie which existed between sales and servicing. The proposal
was that independent repairers would in future be able to get greater access to the
necessary spare parts and technology, thereby encouraging new entrants to join
the market with reduced initial investment costs. While these proposals were
broadly welcomed by groups representing consumers (e.g. the Consumer
Association in the UK), some observers felt that the planned reforms did not go far
enough to weaken the power of the suppliers over the market (see e.g. the editorial in
the Financial Times, 11 January 2002). For instance it appeared to be the case
that while manufacturers would be able to supply cars to supermarkets and other new
retailers, they would not be required by law to do so, suggesting that a market
free-for-all was highly unlikely to emerge in the foreseeable future. Equally the
Commission’s plans appeared to do little to protect dealers from threats to
terminate their franchises should there be a dispute with the supplier. In the event the old block
exemption scheme expired at the end of September 2002 and the new rules began the next day. However, the
majority of the provisions under the EC rules did not come into effect until the following October
(2003) and the ban on
‘location clauses’ - which limit the geographical scope of dealer opera-tions - only came into
effect two years later. Since October 2005 dealers have been free to set up secondary
sales outlets in other areas of the EU, as well as their own countries. This is
expected to stengthen competition between dealers across the Single Market to the advantage
of consumers (e.g. greater choice and reduced prices).
How would you account for the difference in perspective between firms who often complain of government over-interference in business matters and ministers who |
Case study questions
1.
Can you suggest any reasons why the European Commission was willing to
grant
the block exemption in the first place, given that it ran counter to its proposals for a Single Market?
the block exemption in the first place, given that it ran counter to its proposals for a Single Market?
2.
Why might the new reforms make cars cheaper for European consumers?
Case 5 : The sale
of goods on the Internet
The sale of consumer goods
on the Internet (particularly those between European member states) raises a
number of legal issues. First, there is the issue of trust, with-out which the consumer
will not buy; they will need assurance that the seller is genuine, and that they
will get the goods that they believe they have ordered. Second, there is the issue
of consumer rights with respect to the goods in question: what rights exist and do
they vary across Europe? Last, the issue of enforcement: what happens should
anything go wrong?
Information and
trust
Europe recognises the problems of doing
business across the Internet or telephone and it has attempted to address the main stumbling blocks via Directives. The Consumer Protection (Distance Selling) Regulations 2000 attempts to address the
issues of trust in cross-border consumer sales, which may take place over the Internet (or telephone). In short, the consumer needs to know quite a bit of
infor-mation, which they may otherwise have easy access to if they were buying face
to face. Regulation 7 requires inter alia for the seller to identify themselves
and an address must be provided if the goods are to be paid for in advance. Moreover,
a full description of the goods and the final price (inclusive of any taxes) must
also be provided. The seller must also inform the buyer of the right of cancellation available under Regulations 10-12, where the
buyer has a right to cancel the contract for seven days starting on the day
after the consumer receives the goods or services. Failure to inform the
consumer of this right automatically extends the period to three months.
The
cost of returning goods is to be borne by the buyer, and the seller is entitled
to deduct the costs directly flowing from recovery as a restocking fee. All of
this places a considerable obligation on the seller; however, such data should
stem many misunderstandings and so greatly assist consumer faith and confidence
in non-face-to-face sales.Another concern for the consumer is fraud. The
consumer who has paid by credit card will be protected by section 83 of the Consumer Credit Act 1974,
under which a consumer/purchaser is not liable for the debt incurred, if it has been
run up by a third party not acting as the agent of the buyer. The Distance Selling Regulations extend this to debit cards, and remove the ability of the card
issuer to charge the consumer for the first £50 of loss (Regulation 21). Moreover,
section 75 of the Consumer Credit Act 1974 also gives the consumer/buyer a like claim
against the credit card company for any misrepresentation or breach of contract by the seller. This is extremely important in a distance selling transaction, where
the seller may disappear.
What quality and
what rights?
The next issue relates to the quality that may
be expected from goods bought over the Internet. Clearly, if goods have been bought from abroad, the levels of
quality required in other jurisdictions may vary. It is for this reason that Europe has
attempted to standardise the issue of quality and consumer rights, with the Consumer Guarantees Directive (1999/44/EC), thus continuing the push to encour-age cross-border consumer purchases. The implementing Sale and Supply of Goods to Consumer Regulations 2002 came into force in 2003, which not only lays down minimum quality standards, but also provides a series of consumer remedies
which will be common across Europe. The Regulations further amend the Sale of Goods Act 1979. The DTI, whose job it was to incorporate the Directive into domestic
law (by way of delegated legislation) ensured that the pre-existing consumer rights
were maintained, so as not to reduce the overall level of protection available to
con-sumers. The Directive requires goods to be of ‘normal’ quality, or fit for any purpose made known by the seller. This has been taken to be the same as our
pre-existing ‘reasonable quality’ and ‘fitness for purpose’ obligations owed under sections 14(2) and 14(3) of the Sale of Goods Act 1979. Moreover, the
pre-existing remedy of the short-term right to reject is also retained. This right provides
the buyer a short period of time to discover whether the goods are in conformity
with the contract. In practice, it is usually a matter of weeks at most. After that
time has elapsed, the consumer now has four new remedies that did not exist before,
which
are provided in two pairs. These are repair or replacement, or price reduction or rescission. The pre-existing law only gave the consumer a right to damages, which would rarely be exercised in practice. (However, the Small Claims Court would ensure a speedy and cheap means of redress for almost all claims brought.) Now there is a right to a repair or a replacement, so that the consumer is not left with an impractical action for damages over defective goods. The seller must also bear the cost of return of the goods for repair. So such costs must now be factored into any business sales plan. If neither of these remedies is suitable or actioned within a ‘rea- sonable period of time’ then the consumer may rely on the second pair of remedies. Price reduction permits the consumer to claim back a segment of the pur-chase price if the goods are still useable. It is effectively a discount for defective goods. Rescission permits the consumer to reject the goods, but does not get a full refund, as they would under the short-term right to reject. Here money is knocked off for ‘beneficial use’. This is akin to the pre-existing treatment for breaches of durability, where goods have not lasted as long as goods of that type ought reason-ably be expected to last. The level of compensation would take account of the use that the consumer has (if any) been able to put the goods to and a deduction made off the return of the purchase price. However, the issue that must be addressed is as to the length of time that goods may be expected to last. A supplier may state the length of the guarantee period, so a £500 television set guaranteed for one year would have a life expectancy of one year. On the other hand, a consumer may expect a television set to last ten years. Clearly, if the set went wrong after six months, the consumer would only get £250 back if the retailer’s figure was used, but would receive £475 if their own figure was used. It remains to be seen how this provision will work in practice. One problem with distance sales has been that of liability for goods which arrive damaged. The pre-existing domestic law stated that risk would pass to the buyer once the goods were handed over to a third-party carrier. This had the major problem in practice of who would actually be liable for the damage. Carriers would blame the supplier and vice versa. The consumer would be able to sue for the loss, if they were able to determine which party was responsible. In practice, consumers usually went uncompensated and such a worry has put many consumers off buying goods over the Internet. The Sale and Supply of Goods to Consumer Regulations also modify the transfer of risk, so that now the risk remains with the seller until actual delivery. This will clearly lead to a slight increase in the supply of goods to consumers, with the goods usually now being sent by insured delivery. However, this will avoid the prob-lem of who is actually liable and should help to boost confidence.
are provided in two pairs. These are repair or replacement, or price reduction or rescission. The pre-existing law only gave the consumer a right to damages, which would rarely be exercised in practice. (However, the Small Claims Court would ensure a speedy and cheap means of redress for almost all claims brought.) Now there is a right to a repair or a replacement, so that the consumer is not left with an impractical action for damages over defective goods. The seller must also bear the cost of return of the goods for repair. So such costs must now be factored into any business sales plan. If neither of these remedies is suitable or actioned within a ‘rea- sonable period of time’ then the consumer may rely on the second pair of remedies. Price reduction permits the consumer to claim back a segment of the pur-chase price if the goods are still useable. It is effectively a discount for defective goods. Rescission permits the consumer to reject the goods, but does not get a full refund, as they would under the short-term right to reject. Here money is knocked off for ‘beneficial use’. This is akin to the pre-existing treatment for breaches of durability, where goods have not lasted as long as goods of that type ought reason-ably be expected to last. The level of compensation would take account of the use that the consumer has (if any) been able to put the goods to and a deduction made off the return of the purchase price. However, the issue that must be addressed is as to the length of time that goods may be expected to last. A supplier may state the length of the guarantee period, so a £500 television set guaranteed for one year would have a life expectancy of one year. On the other hand, a consumer may expect a television set to last ten years. Clearly, if the set went wrong after six months, the consumer would only get £250 back if the retailer’s figure was used, but would receive £475 if their own figure was used. It remains to be seen how this provision will work in practice. One problem with distance sales has been that of liability for goods which arrive damaged. The pre-existing domestic law stated that risk would pass to the buyer once the goods were handed over to a third-party carrier. This had the major problem in practice of who would actually be liable for the damage. Carriers would blame the supplier and vice versa. The consumer would be able to sue for the loss, if they were able to determine which party was responsible. In practice, consumers usually went uncompensated and such a worry has put many consumers off buying goods over the Internet. The Sale and Supply of Goods to Consumer Regulations also modify the transfer of risk, so that now the risk remains with the seller until actual delivery. This will clearly lead to a slight increase in the supply of goods to consumers, with the goods usually now being sent by insured delivery. However, this will avoid the prob-lem of who is actually liable and should help to boost confidence.
Enforcement
Enforcement
for domestic sales is relatively straightforward. Small-scale consumer claims can be
dealt with expeditiously and cheaply under the Small Claims Court. Here claims
under £5000 for contract-based claims are brought in a special court intended to
keep costs down by keeping the lawyers’ out of the court room, as a vic-torious party
cannot claim for their lawyers’ expenses. The judge will conduct the case in a more
‘informal’ manner, and will seek to discover the legal issues by ques-tioning
both parties, so no formal knowledge of the law is required. The total cost of
such a case, even if it is lost, is the cost of issuing the proceedings
(approximately 10 per cent of the value claimed) and the other side’s
‘reasonable expenses’. Expenses must be kept down, and a judge will not award value which
has been deliberately run up, such first-class rail travel and stays in five star
hotels.
Residents of Northampton have hosted a trial of an online claims procedure, so that
claims may now be made via the Internet. (www.courtservice.gov.uk outlines the
procedure for MCOL, or Money Claims Online.) Cases will normally be held in the
defendant’s court, unless the complainant is a consumer and the defendant a
business. Enforcement is the
weak point in the European legislation, for there is, as yet, no European-wide Small Claims
Court dealing with transnational European transac-tions. The consumer is
thus forced to contemplate expensive civil action abroad in a foreign language, perhaps
where no such small claims system exists - a pointless measure for all but the
most expensive of consumer purchases. The only redress lies in EEJ-Net, the European
Extra-Judicial Network, which puts the complainant in touch with any applicable
professional or trade body in the supplier’s home member state. It does require the
existence of such a body, which is unlikely if the transac-tion is for electrical
goods, which is one of the most popular types of Internet purchase. Therefore, until
Europe provides a Euro Small Claims Court, the consumer cross-border buyer may
have many rights, but no effective means of enforcement.
Until then it would appear that section 75 of the Consumer Credit Act 1974, which gives the buyer the same remedies against their credit card company as against the seller, is the only effective means of redress.
Until then it would appear that section 75 of the Consumer Credit Act 1974, which gives the buyer the same remedies against their credit card company as against the seller, is the only effective means of redress.
Case study questions
1.
Consider the checklist of data which a distance seller must provide to
a consumer
purchaser. Is this putting too heavy a burden on sellers?
purchaser. Is this putting too heavy a burden on sellers?
2.
Is a consumer distance buyer any better off after the European
legislation?
3. Are there any remaining issues that must be
tackled to increase European cross-
border consumer trade?
border consumer trade?
www.answersheets.in
info.answersheets@gmail.com
info@answersheets.in
+91 95030-94040
No comments:
Post a Comment